246 / PARADOXES or FORCED LABOR not in the United States but abroad). It is of some interest to note that the pecuniary benefits of gang production were much more widely diffused than the losses suffered by slaves. For every slave working in the cotton fields, there were hundreds of consumers of cotton. This means that the average annual gain to a consumer was quite small. Indeed, for every dollar gained by a typical consumer of cotton cloth, there was a slave laboring somewhere under the hot south- ern sun who would lose at least $400. Some antebellum critics of slavery recognized that the system was being perpetuated by the greed of consumers. Robert Russell, one of the most acute of the British travelers to the South, believed that slavery was “a necessary evil attending upon the great good of cheap cotton.” How in- dignant Olmsted was at this charge. That claim, he re- torted, was sheer nonsense. He devoted a full chapter in The Cotton Kingdom to the refutation of Russell, arguing that slavery raised rather than lowered the price of cotton. How widespread this self-delusion was, is difficult to ascertain. Certainly not all of the antislavery politicians who railed against southern bondage, while they continued to consume cotton and resisted attempts to tax it, were naive. At least some of these politicians thought that a totalboycott of south- ern cotton, sugar, tobacco, and rice would have brought an end to slavery. Russell was not the only one who held this view. While Senator James H. Hammond undoubtedly over- estimated how far the South could go before it provoked war, he clearly understood the hypocrisy in the position of many critics of the South when he proclaimed: No, you dare not make war on cotton. No power on earth dares to make war upon it. Cotton is king. Until lately the Bank of England was king, but she tried to put her screws as usual, the’ fall before the last, upon the cotton crop, and was utterly van- quished. The last power has been conquered. Who can doubt, that has looked at recent events, that cotton is supreme? . -v ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE SOUTH, 1840-1860 / *247 The Course of Economic Growth in the South, 1840-1860 The construction of regional income accounts for the nineteenth century, like the estimation of regional eificiency indexes, is an arduous task. Work on these accounts for the census years between 1840 and 1860, which was launched in the early 1950s, is still going on today. Table 4 presents the regional income estimates which have now been in use for about half a decade. A recent paper has suggested that the estimate of southern income for 1840 may be too low; the same criticism may also apply to the figure for 1860. If these proposed corrections hold up, it will be necessary to alter some of the details of the analysis that follows, but the main thrust of the argument will not be affected. Rather, the proposed corrections will merely serve to strengthen the argument. Table 4 shows that in both 1840 and 1860 per capita income in the North was higher thanin the South. In 1840 the South had an average income which was only,69 per- cent that of the North’s. In 1860 southern pericapita in- come was still only 73 percent as high as in the North. These figures might appear to sustain Helper’s conten- tion that the South was a poverty—ridden, stagnant economy in the process of sinking into “comparative imbecility and obscurity"; that under the burden of slavery the South had been reduced to the status of a colonial nation — “the de- pendency of a mother country.” No such inference is war- ranted, however, merely because of the existence of a 25 percent gap between the North and the South in the level of per capita income in 1860. Before any conclusion can be drawn, it must first be determined whether the gap means that, by the standards of the time, the South was poor or that the North was extraordinarily rich. Progress toward the resolution of this issue can be made